Announcement

Collapse
No announcement yet.

Inflation is a process, not an event - Part I: Three inflation fallacies - Eric Janszen

Collapse
X
 
  • Filter
  • Time
  • Show
Clear All
new posts

  • Inflation is a process, not an event - Part I: Three inflation fallacies - Eric Janszen


    Inflation is a process, not an event - Part I: Three inflation fallacies

    • What have we forgotten the nature of inflation since the 1970s?
    • Where is the U.S. economy in the transition from low to higher inflation?

    Monetary authorities and economists focus on inflation expectations because inflation expectations have a way of becoming reality over time. Inflation expectations, after falling hard in 2008, have been steadily rising since early 2009, and actual inflation has tracked expectations, with a time lag, as usual. Recently, however, inflation and inflation expectations have started to dip again. Is it time for the Fed to hit the deflation spiral panic button?

    Expectations of future inflation are informed by the past experience of consumers, both recent and distant. The longer inflation remains tame, the longer consumers extrapolate low inflation into the future even as evidence to the contrary begins to reveal itself. Wage and manufactured goods price inflation has been so low for so long that most of us can’t recognize the shift to a more inflationary environment as it is happening today, but it is, as we’ll show.

    Study the relationship between inflation expectations and all-items price indexes over time and you’ll find that consumers form their short-term expectations of all-items price inflation based largely on current energy prices, and for good reason; all-items price inflation tracks energy price inflation closely as a major input cost both to producers and consumers.


    For all practical purposes, today’s consumer expectations for inflation a year from now are the same as today’s energy prices. That’s why monetary authorities focus on energy prices to manipulate both consumer and producer inflation expectations. As a deflation-fighting tool, abandoning the strong dollar policy in 2008 and allowing the dollar to depreciate was the most powerful weapon that policy makers had in the arsenal of deflation fighting tools in a zero interest rate environment. Rising oil import prices sent inflation price signals into the economy, pushing up the price of domestically produced oil and spreading price inflation throughout the entire commodity complex.

    Historically, after a period of rising energy price inflation and declining unemployment growth, the Fed steps in to lower inflation expectations by talking about raising interest rates, and then, depending on the market’s response to the jaw boning, follows through sometime thereafter.


    The Fed Rate Hike Zone formula goes something like this:
    If the rate of unemployment growth falls to 10% year over year and stops declining, and energy price inflation rises to a 5% annual rate, then begin a tightening cycle. Of course, there are many other variables in the Fed’s decision formula, such as money growth and the ratio of non-performing loans, and no one but the Fed knows exactly what the formula is, but energy prices and unemployment are certainly key factors.
    As high and inflationary as energy prices are today, they have stabilized and over the past few months and the rate of price growth, while still positive, has started to decline. It’s too early to call this a trend; energy prices have been so volatile due both to giant fluctuations in demand during the recession as well as to economic policy measures taken to cope with the recession that it is impossible to say at this time which way energy prices will move over the next six months. That is the crux of the Fed’s dilemma.

    As the unemployment growth rate continues to fall, even if the unemployment level doesn’t decline substantially, and if energy prices resume their rise then within a year, the Fed will be back in the hike zone. Even if energy prices don’t rise further and simply remain in the $70s – recall $60 oil was called a “bubble” by Soros and others as recently as 2006 – the kind of inflation that we have experienced for several years now will begin to influence inflation expectations for years to come.

    Stealth Inflation

    The inflation we have experienced since early 2009 has so far not appeared as rising all-items prices but exhibits itself in ways that are familiar to older Americans who remember the early 1970s in the U.S. Citizens of countries that have experienced a transition from a low to a higher inflation environment due to a weakening currency will also recognize the symptoms.

    To the uninitiated, the mix of price and quality changes of various goods and services gives rise to confusion and nonsensical terms like “bi-deflation.” The purchasing power of income and savings is either rising or it is falling. It cannot be doing both at once, although a decline in purchasing power is expressed differently in various goods and services prices depending on many factors. Here we tackle the three common inflation fallacies believed by Americans who have forgotten what inflation is all about.

    Fallacy #1: When unemployment rises, inflation falls

    We’ve locked horns for years with analysts who can’t imagine how inflation can rise when jobs are scarce. Where is the competition for goods going to come from to drive up prices if consumers are cutting back on their spending to conserve savings, either because they are unemployed or are afraid they will be soon? That is certainly the environment that we see ourselves in today.

    This sounds reasonable until you consider the case of India today where both unemployment and inflation are rising together.


    How is rising inflation and rising unemployment possible? Because inflation is not only a factor of the supply and demand for goods but also of the supply and demand for the money used to buy the goods. Demand is determined not only by the level of desire of consumers to purchase goods but also their means to do so, the purchasing power of their income and savings. This leads us to the second fallacy of inflation. Also, producers may cut goods supply even more quickly than consumers reduce demand, resulting in a goods supply/demand imbalance albeit at a lower level than before the recession.

    Inflation Fallacy #2: Inflation results from too much money chasing too few goods

    Four variables determine the way inflation is exhibited in prices:
    1. Supply goods
    2. Demand for goods
    3. Supply of money
    4. Demand for money

    The deflationary price impact of falling consumer demand on a fixed quantity of goods supplied by producers is intuitive: prices fall as producers compete for fewer consumers. Likewise, if the demand for money rises faster than the money supply, the value of money rises and the result is deflationary.

    Two dynamics trip up most observers.

    The first is the interaction of these four variables of inflation with each other as activist economic policy makers interfere with the market that would, if left to its own devices, allow prices to fall to meet the new lower level of demand.


    Money at zero maturity, a measure of the money supply closely watched by the Fed, averaged 10% growth rate during the recession, but has been declining overall since the start of the recession.

    This is typical of periods of weakness in the banking system when the ratio of non-performing loans are rising and the effectiveness of monetary policy to increase the money supply through the banking system is limited.


    During recessions when NPL increased, the rate of MZM growth decreased. Recently, the level of NLPs started to decline and the velocity of MZM increased.


    The view of inflation inevitably arising from weak consumer demand in periods of rising unemployment is muddied by policies designed to stimulate money growth and delays between money growth an the appearance of inflation.

    The second dynamic of the four inflation variables that confuses most observers is the ability of producers to quickly withdraw supply in anticipation of declining demand. This not the case in the 1930s when computer analysis tools to forecast future demand were unavailable. This is reflected in the rapid increase in capacity utilization since the official end of the recession in late 2009.


    If rising inflation can attend rising unemployment, then it should not surprise readers to learn that low unemployment and rising wages can co-exist with consumer price deflation. Consider the case of Japan since 1999.

    Consumer price inflation fell...

    ...while wages grew.

    This is why most Japanese will tell you that they have experienced the past 20 years as a period of rising living standards. This leads us to our third inflation fallacy.

    Inflation Fallacy #3: Inflation always causes all-items prices rise at the same time


    This is the case after inflation expectations have been rising for an extended period, usually several years and expectations of high inflation are deeply imbedded, but not during transitions from low to higher inflation. At first, inflation appears in those industries where producers have regained pricing power. An industry with pricing power is one that has consolidated to a single, dominant player that serves a market. For example, Walmart recently raised prices 6% in one month:
    Wal-Mart Quietly Raises Prices
    August 10, 2010

    Wal-Mart Stores (WMT), which for years has touted its prowess at lowering prices, has been doing the opposite as it tries to bolster its bottom line amid stagnating sales.

    A JPMorgan Chase (JPM) study of a Walmart Supercenter in Virginia found that the world's largest retailer has raised prices by nearly 6% on average over the past six weeks, according to the New York Post. Reuters says it was the biggest sequential increase since JPMorgan started the study in January 2009.

    Some Prices Hiked Over 60%

    Some of the price hikes were considerably larger. For instance, the price of a 32-ounce bottle of Windex household cleaner jumped 50%, a 12-ounce box of Quaker Oats instant grits climbed 65% and a 50-ounce container of Tide detergent rose by more than 50%.
    In Japan, some industries experienced deflation while others have seen relatively high levels of inflation.


    While Wholesale and Retail, Manufacturing, Transportation industries experienced deflation between 1990 and 1999 ranging from a cumulative -4% to -10% deflation while the Construction, Real Estate, and Services industries experienced a cumulative 11% to 17% inflation. The determinant factor: the ratio of non-performing loans (NPL) relative to assets of banks lending to those industries.

    Here in the U.S., early in our debt deflation process, there is a pattern of per-industry deflation and inflation developing. But for reasons of a more dynamic and self-correcting banking sector, the NPL problem for the U.S. will not be as great a deflationary factor here.

    For example, Walmart raised prices in response to weak consumer demand. That may strike some readers as backwards, but remember that as input costs rise, the company that can maintain the highest per-unit profit margins and wins the positive cash flow contest in the long run. If input costs remain high, producers and retailers must raise prices eventually, the most efficient producers, wholesalers and retailers the least. We previously documented the other strategy of producers and suppliers to increase per-unit profitability, such as by reducing the size of portions in packaged products and the quality of ingredients.

    Consumers today are reluctant to make purchase decisions unless they perceive that they are getting a “deal.” At first glance this appears to be classic deflationary consumer behavior: purchase decisions are generally delayed by consumers who expect falling prices, which expectations are met by falling prices as the aggregate impact of the waiting behavior produces the expected result, a lower price as producers rush to meet the consumer’s demand for a bargain because they have fewer dollars to spend, or are consumers trying to stretch a dollar of income that buys increasingly less, or both?

    Consumer behavior in an early transition from low to higher inflation varies depending on product. For many big-ticket consumer items, such as autos and major appliances, there is no urgency to go out and buy a product before the price rises.

    Take autos, for example. Sales unit volumes collapsed during the recession. As you’d expect, prices fell, too.


    Note, however, that even thought the Personal Consumption Expenditures price index for autos declined in line with unit volume, import prices did not. The reason is that exporters do not tend to lower prices as much as domestic producers do to meet lower market demand from an export market. They prefer, if they can, to increase sales in other stronger import markets. You can see a similar process with major appliances.


    Prices on a PCE basis fell hard during the recession and have only recently begun to recover, but import prices of major appliances stabilized in the fall of 2009 as exporters adjusted to rising demand elsewhere.

    Also, the auto industry’s loss was the auto parts industry’s gain, as car owners and auto repair shops increased their purchases of parts to repair existing cars to keep them on the road longer. In this case, the domestic PCE price index increased faster than the import index.


    Import prices are recovering to pre-recession levels.


    Any attempt to depict the current environment as deflationary misses the devil in the details. High energy import prices, rising capacity utilization and velocity of money, and a leveling off of NPLs are typical of an inflationary not a deflationary price environment. In Part II we look deeper to find additional reasons for Bernanke to talk up deflation while Keoll dissents with worry that the U.S. economy faces the opposite problem, inflation that may quickly turn into an inflation spiral that will be nearly as hard to manage in an environment of high unemployment as it was in the mid 1970s, but with the additional complication of asset price deflation.


    Inflation is a process, not an event - Part II: Why Keoll is worried

    • Why is Hoeing worried?
    • Will anti-asset price deflation policy trump commodity and wage inflation policy?


    The primary stated mission of the central bank is to maintain commodity and wage price stability in the Productive Economy through adjustment to the money supply via interest rates and other means. As we explained to readers during the housing bubble, an unstated mission of the Fed is to promote asset price inflation in the FIRE Economy through interest rate policy and lack of enforcement of existing regulations of lenders, and lack of new regulations of new, destabilizing financial products.

    The result of the Fed’s “successful” execution of this dual mission: low commodity and wage inflation and a housing bubble. Some day asset price inflation will be regarded by central bankers as being as detrimental to economic growth as commodity and wage inflation but we’re not there yet. We can look forward to several more years of government price supports of assets, with worries about commodity price inflation kept on the back burner.


    The Fed’s asset price inflation mission conflicted with the Fed’s additional role as protector the banking and financial system stability. After the collapse of the housing bubble brought down the private credit markets and nearly collapsed the banking system, without any admission of failure the Fed’s mission abruptly changed.

    The Fed’s new mission is first and foremost to prevent asset price deflation in the FIRE Economy from spilling over into the Productive Economy via the credit markets and banking system. Commodity and wage inflation are now secondary concerns, and are believed to “take care of themselves” as long as unemployment remains high. As we have seen in the case of India in Part I, counting on unemployment to tame inflation is a dangerous gamble. As we shall see in our analysis of the transition from low to high inflation in the 1970s period and compare it to the current era, that assumption may be especially perilous today. more... ($ubscription)

    Tulip Select: The Investment Thesis for the Next Cycle™
    __________________________________________________

    To receive the iTulip Newsletter or iTulip Alerts, Join our FREE Email Mailing List

    Copyright © iTulip, Inc. 1998 - 2010 All Rights Reserved

    All information provided "as is" for informational purposes only, not intended for trading purposes or advice. Nothing appearing on this website should be considered a recommendation to buy or to sell any security or related financial instrument. iTulip, Inc. is not liable for any informational errors, incompleteness, or delays, or for any actions taken in reliance on information contained herein. Full Disclaimer
    Last edited by FRED; August 16, 2010, 06:58 PM.

  • #2
    Re: Inflation is a process, not an event - Part I: Three inflation fallacies - Eric Janszen

    What have we forgotten the nature of inflation since the 1970s?

    Fix this

    Comment


    • #3
      Re: Inflation is a process, not an event - Part I: Three inflation fallacies - Eric Janszen

      Originally posted by a warren View Post
      What have we forgotten the nature of inflation since the 1970s?

      Fix this
      a warren, do you mean: "I believe there is an error with the said sentence, can you please correct it"?

      Better yet, pm FRED with your request and it will be "fix this" in a few hours (I do it all the time).

      Comment


      • #4
        Re: Inflation is a process, not an event - Part I: Three inflation fallacies - Eric Janszen

        Originally posted by LargoWinch View Post
        Better yet, pm FRED
        Good advice.

        Though I will confess to almost responding to a warren's post with a terse but supportive "+1" reply, for this particular glitch was rather prominent.
        Most folks are good; a few aren't.

        Comment


        • #5
          Re: Inflation is a process, not an event - Part I: Three inflation fallacies - Eric Janszen

          Originally posted by EJ View Post
          As the unemployment growth rate continues to fall, even if the unemployment level doesn’t decline substantially, and if energy prices resume their rise then within a year, the Fed will be back in the hike zone. Even if energy prices don’t rise further and simply remain in the $70s[/COLOR] – recall $60 oil was called a “bubble” by Soros and others as recently as 2006 – the kind of inflation that we have experienced for several years now will begin to influence inflation expectations for years to come.
          EJ appears to be saying that he expects the Fed to start raising interest rates, even without significant changes to unemployment or energy prices. His view of future Fed action has changed coarse, while the economic indicators (we have been told to watch) are stagnant.

          The Fed will (of course) raise rates at some point; when rates are at zero, there is only one direction for them to go. But I find EJ's explanation for this happening anytime soon to be lacking. Certainly, it flies in the face of his earlier analysis.

          Comment


          • #6
            Re: Inflation is a process, not an event - Part I: Three inflation fallacies - Eric Janszen

            Originally posted by dummass View Post
            EJ appears to be saying that he expects the Fed to start raising interest rates, even without significant changes to unemployment or energy prices. His view of future Fed action has changed coarse, while the economic indicators (we have been told to watch) are stagnant.

            The Fed will (of course) raise rates at some point; when rates are at zero, there is only one direction for them to go. But I find EJ's explanation for this happening anytime soon to be lacking. Certainly, it flies in the face of his earlier analysis.
            read part ii. it says that although we're entering "the hike zone," it won't happen because of a. political pressure, b. risk to the rickety fire economy [a risk that didn't exist in past cycles].

            Comment


            • #7
              Re: Inflation is a process, not an event - Part I: Three inflation fallacies - Eric Janszen

              Originally posted by EJ
              To the uninitiated, the mix of price and quality changes of various goods and services gives rise to confusion and nonsensical terms like “bi-deflation.” The purchasing power of income and savings is either rising or it is falling. It cannot be doing both at once, although a decline in purchasing power is expressed differently in various goods and services prices depending on many factors.
              I might suggest not painting those holding other views as uninitiated or their terms as nonsensical. That sounds gratuitously ad hominem to my ear.

              To the point you're making here, it reads to me (given in particular your dismissal of the term "bi-deflation") almost as if you're saying it's inflation or deflation, not both.

              Giordano Bruno, in a post on Neithercorp, linked to from the two recent iTulip posts Dollar's Antemortem and U.S. Dollar Now Ripe For Catastrophic Devaluation, comments on this about as clearly as anyone I've seen, stating:
              The inflation vs. deflation debate has been raging for nearly three years, but I suspect that when all is said and done, we will find that both sides in a sense were correct. The people who consistently miss the mark on what is truly going on in the economy are those who blindly insist that this is an either/or situation. The fact is, we are seeing symptoms of BOTH deflation and inflation simultaneously. Deflation in jobs, stocks, real estate, and wages. Inflation in energy, food, and commodities.
              Most folks are good; a few aren't.

              Comment


              • #8
                Re: Inflation is a process, not an event - Part I: Three inflation fallacies - Eric Janszen

                For the past year, the effects of government stimulus have played a large part in iTulip's economic analysis. They had a chart from Goldman that projected the affects of stimulus on GDP tapering off in 2010 and going negative by the second quarter of this year. Is this no longer relevant? Does this no longer account for why we have seen improvement in the economy?

                As the affects of stimulus recede (projected for the second half) and its affects on GDP are diminished, won't this also affect the recent improvements to imports and capacity utilization (as sited above)? Strength in imports and capacity utilization would appear to be symptoms, not causes, for increased demand.

                If this recent increase in demand has legs, and stimulus was not the primary cause, then what were the contributing factors?

                Comment


                • #9
                  Re: Inflation is a process, not an event - Part I: Three inflation fallacies - Eric Janszen

                  Originally posted by dummass View Post
                  For the past year, the effects of government stimulus have played a large part in iTulip's economic analysis. They had a chart from Goldman that projected the affects of stimulus on GDP tapering off in 2010 and going negative by the second quarter of this year. Is this no longer relevant? Does this no longer account for why we have seen improvement in the economy?

                  As the affects of stimulus recede (projected for the second half) and its affects on GDP are diminished, won't this also affect the recent improvements to imports and capacity utilization (as sited above)? Strength in imports and capacity utilization would appear to be symptoms, not causes, for increased demand.

                  If this recent increase in demand has legs, and stimulus was not the primary cause, then what were the contributing factors?
                  i think the next round of stimulus will be purely from the fed, as the fiscal authorities are politically hamstrung. the big question in my mind is timing: how fast the negative swing in the effect of the last round of stimulus unfolds, and whether - if it's soon - the fed feels free to launch qe ii big time right before an election.

                  Comment


                  • #10
                    Re: Inflation is a process, not an event - Part I: Three inflation fallacies - Eric Janszen

                    Originally posted by jk View Post
                    read part ii.
                    Thanks JK, I will read part two, but not now. At the moment I'm still digesting part one. It would be rare for EJ's articles (part one vs part two) to contradict each other. Typically EJ's analyses, in part two, will dive deeper into the specifics or expand the breadth of his analysis, but would not negate the thesis of part one. Otherwise, he runs the risk of leading the non-payed subscribers astray. If this is an unintended circumstance, I'm sure he would want to rectify it.

                    Comment


                    • #11
                      Re: Inflation is a process, not an event - Part I: Three inflation fallacies - Eric Janszen

                      Originally posted by dummass View Post
                      Thanks JK, I will read part two, but not now. At the moment I'm still digesting part one. It would be rare for EJ's articles (part one vs part two) to contradict each other. Typically EJ's analyses, in part two, will dive deeper into the specifics or expand the breadth of his analysis, but would not negate the thesis of part one. Otherwise, he runs the risk of leading the non-payed subscribers astray. If this is an unintended circumstance, I'm sure he would want to rectify it.
                      i just posted an interesting piece by andy xie, which boils down to
                      developed world deflation + stimulus leakage => emerging world inflation => global inflation via commodity [and other tradeables] prices
                      http://www.itulip.com/forums/showthr...645#post171645

                      Comment


                      • #12
                        Re: Inflation is a process, not an event - Part I: Three inflation fallacies - Eric Janszen

                        Excellent analysis. I think too many of the prognosticators focus on either the supply demand factor or the monetary factors of inflation,but not both. Since enegry costs are closely tied to inflation expectations, I would like to get EJ's take on commodity inflation due to increased market speculation. There has been much talk of the amount of dollars rolling forward in futures now that it can actually drive the physical price.

                        Anyone who grocery shops regularly could tell you that prices have gone up. 100 bucks doesn't go far these days. But how much of that is due to monetary inflation versus price inflation?

                        Comment


                        • #13
                          Re: Inflation is a process, not an event - Part I: Three inflation fallacies - Eric Janszen

                          Originally posted by EJ
                          How is rising inflation and rising unemployment possible? Because inflation is not only a factor of the supply and demand for goods but also of the supply and demand for the money used to buy the goods.
                          aka money printing. This is what is happening in India. severe Food Inflation in things we need. Though wages have increased 3 times since 2001, food prices have increased a little more than 3 times. My worry is whether food inflation will be greater than wage inflation in India. Then people will feel the pain.

                          So far I did not feel the pain of food price in USA. But lately, I am starting to take note. Goat meat from my local halal butcher was $3.99/lb a year ago , now $5.99/lb. If it rises further, I may pool with others and buy an whole Goat for $150(approx 60 lbs meat) and divide. Beef creeped from $3.29/lb to $3.90/lb. Egg/Bread has gone up too. The only thing that have not gone up is milk- $2.29/gallon.
                          Last edited by sishya; August 20, 2010, 02:33 PM.

                          Comment


                          • #14
                            Re: Inflation is a process, not an event - Part I: Three inflation fallacies - Eric Janszen

                            Originally posted by jk View Post
                            i think the next round of stimulus will be purely from the fed, as the fiscal authorities are politically hamstrung. the big question in my mind is timing: how fast the negative swing in the effect of the last round of stimulus unfolds, and whether - if it's soon - the fed feels free to launch qe ii big time right before an election.
                            My impression is that QE doesn't work as an effective short term stimulus like fiscal measures can. The Fed might be pushing on a string with QE II.

                            Comment


                            • #15
                              Re: Inflation is a process, not an event - Part I: Three inflation fallacies - Eric Janszen

                              Who could have known?
                              Wal-Mart CEO Bill Simon expects inflation

                              U.S. consumers face "serious" inflation in the months ahead for clothing, food and other products, the head of Wal-Mart's U.S. operations warned Wednesday.

                              The world's largest retailer is working with suppliers to minimize the effect of cost increases and believes its low-cost business model will position it better than its competitors.

                              Still, inflation is "going to be serious," Wal-Mart U.S. CEO Bill Simon said during a meeting with USA TODAY's editorial board. "We're seeing cost increases starting to come through at a pretty rapid rate." more...
                              Ed.

                              Comment

                              Working...
                              X